Optimism bias and the pandemic economy

[ad_1]

Optimism

Something like this optimism bias is strongly encoded into how we tend to think about economics. It’s not just a modelling problem: the belief that the wider environment is stable and can therefore be ignored is foundational to conventional “neoclassical” economics as such.

Notoriously, if the environment appears at all, it tends to turn up as a “externality” – as something separate from the economy and whatever model of the economy we are using, but which then intrudes.

So imagine, for example, that a pencil factory pollutes the air, and this air pollution causes more respiratory illnesses, raising the costs of healthcare elsewhere. The environment here appears after the fact of the economic activity. It is strictly external to that activity.

This is, as generations of ecological economists have pointed out, kind of nonsense.

Clearly we inhabit the physical environment before we start to build factories and poison the air: we are not, sadly, ethereal creatures of pure thought and beauty, but have to eke out an existence scrubbing around in grubby material reality, and this is fundamental to everything we do.

Externalities

But by excluding the environment from how we think about the economy – unless forced to put it back in, once, say, childhood asthma cases become so frequent as to be unavoidable – we are making the implicit assumption that it doesn’t matter.

I don’t mean as a moral point. I mean it as an economic modelling point: that by excluding the environment, you have to also assume that the environment is irrelevant for all future conclusions in the model – that the environment is a passive support for whatever economic activity it is that you want to think about.

Incidentally, it’s a problem that persists across the discipline, in a weaker form. The schools of thought outside of neoclassicism, like post-Keynesianism or Marxism, tend also to simply take a stable environment – and therefore the prospect of unlimited future growth – as read. It’s an unexamined assumption of the model.

Now this may be fine if the environment, as a general rule, is broadly stable: that the environment can be thought of as sort of passive sink that we may, if we wish, decide to include in our modelling and our conceptions of the economy, but that we don’t have to.

You don’t have to include so-called externalities: by their nature, they are assumed to be external. It’s a matter of choice. If we are considering economic growth, we can make the strong assumption that a trend rate of growth exists, and whatever shocks do occur – those “externalities” again! – their effects will dissipate over time.

Zoonotic

What if that no longer applies? There’s no real reason to think covid-19 is the last such pandemic we will encounter, for example.

The most likely culprits for further outbreaks are the influenza viruses that circulate amongst our livestock: mutating rapidly, in close proximity to potential human hosts, it has been influenza that occupies pandemic planning.

But even here, given the features of influenza relative to SARS-Cov-2 – lacking, perhaps most importantly, the asymptomatic but infectious period of covid-19 that has caused (and will cause) such mayhem – may well make it somewhat more containable, or at least make containment something closer to a forest fire than this slow-burn chronic social illness we now have.

That said, given that SARS-Cov-2 is so well adapted to the kind of society we live in, it does at least seem plausible that, should another zoonotic breakthrough occur and spread, it will have similar features: that if we find ourselves on the wrong side of a future pandemic, it will also have features similar to SARS-Cov-2, because we live in a society that SARS-Cov-2 is a good fit for. To the extent we ourselves have adapted to covid-19, this is less likely, of course.

Wealth

So we probably won’t get an environmental calamity with quite the same destructive features of covid-19 in the future; or, at least, if we do we would need to be profoundly unlucky.

To put it in the crude terms of conventional economics: it does not seem likely that a one-shot global productivity reduction will occur because of a future environmental disaster, although this cannot be entirely ruled out.

But we can be near-certain that the succession of extreme weather events and natural disasters will increase in pace, as they have done for the last fifty years or so.

The cumulative effect of continual and increasing numbers of environmental crises is to radically increase the costs and difficulties of economic actions: we will find it hard to simply produce goods, as we are presently finding with (say) semiconductors; we will find it harder to deliver services, as we are finding with covid-19; we will find ourselves devoting more and more of our collective wealth to dealing with the costs of recurrent environmental emergencies.

Capitalism

If we take the environmental forecasts seriously, nothing in this says economic growth will return to trend. More volatility of growth in general – more peaks and troughs as the economy is beset by environmental disasters – and lower growth on average is surely a more plausible prediction.

This would be a break in the functioning of capitalism, equivalent to its initial drive into “inorganic” sources of energy like coal in the late eighteenth and early nineteenth century.

As Andreas Malm’s very brilliant Fossil Capital argues, it was the pursuit of stability against a dependency on the environment that saw early industrial capitalism switch from lower cost but erratic water power to higher cost but consistent coal and, later, oil.

This insight – that capitalism will substitute greater control for lower costs – is of exceptional importance, and I’ll return to it at a later date. For now, note that Michal Kalecki makes the same underlying point in his classic 1943 essay on full employment.

A capitalism buffeted by successive environmental disasters starts to look rather like its early, pre-industrial form: not able to produce regularly and systematically, but suddenly subject to forces that remained always outside of its control.

Redistribution

The problem of labour – which, annoyingly, remains the problem of managing people who, annoyingly, may have their own ideas about being managed – would be joined by and indeed, increasingly is being joined by, the problem of managing the environment.

Not one of extracting and using resources, which industrial capitalism is built around and upon; nor even the problem of managing specific, localised environmental problems – installing air-conditioning, say, where typical temperatures are otherwise too hot for office work – but something appearing at the macroeconomic level as a generalised instability.

Throw in, as we should, the capacity of the financial system to reinforce and redistribute that instability – taking, via the power of credit, failures in one part of the world and turning them into financial crises everywhere – and the prospects for future economic growth dwindle further. Regulators are increasingly alert to the prospect of environmental instability producing financial turmoil.

Add, more speculatively, the extraordinary resources being devoted to technologies that are just not very good at adding to growth in the aggregate – those immense investments in information technology that, one day soon, will surely produce a step-change in measured productivity, just not today – and it’s hard to sustain the sunny optimism that a two percent trend rate of growth implies.

But if the economy isn’t going to grow like it used to, the question of redistribution comes to the fore.

Power

It’s no longer enough to either openly as in “trickle down” or implicitly – as in most versions of social democracy – assume growth will deliver for most people, because if it is hitting hard constraints, it won’t – not in the medium- to longer-term, at least.

Expect more squabbles over redistribution to come; the current arguments around inflation are merely a precursor to them.

Jo Michell has an excellent, short overview of why wage rises are to be welcomed, but interest rates rises opposed, in dealing with the current and ongoing bout of inflation.

If this alarming Financial Times interview is anything to go by, the Bank of England’s new chief economist, Huw Pill, could do with reading it. Otherwise, stagflation plus pandemic plus environmental collapse will be a fun combination in the next few years, I’m sure.

Richard Seymour has been pursuing the same thought about our likely future for some time. You can read his latest on the supply crisis over at his Patreon here.

Meanwhile, in scenes that I think/hope will be repeated in this country, the US is in the early stages of a strike wave. Across the developed world, the combination of dislocation from lockdown, some continuing pandemic restrictions, but a surge in consumer demand is causing labour markets to tighten.

For the first time in two generations or more, the balance of bargaining power is shifting in favour of labour and against capital. This is turning into wage rises, and – in a reverse of a decades-long pattern under neoliberalism – in both the US and the UK it is lower-paid workers who seem to be gaining most. Sharon Graham’s first address to Unite’s Policy Conference as the union’s General Secretary is a crucial statement of strategy here.

This Author

James Meadway is an economist and former political advisor. Sign up for his new newsletter.

[ad_2]

Original Post

12 thoughts on “Optimism bias and the pandemic economy

  • 16 December 2023 at 11:01 pm
    Permalink

    I’m not sure why but this website is loading incredibly slow for me. Is anyone else having this problem or is it a issue on my end? I’ll check back later and see if the problem still exists.

    Reply
  • 20 January 2024 at 7:27 am
    Permalink

    Great website. Lots of useful info here. I’m sending it to some buddies ans also sharing in delicious. And certainly, thanks on your sweat!

    Reply
  • 11 March 2024 at 9:22 pm
    Permalink

    You made some good points there. I did a search on the subject matter and found most individuals will approve with your site.

    Reply
  • 21 March 2024 at 5:35 am
    Permalink

    I discovered your weblog site on google and test a number of of your early posts. Proceed to keep up the excellent operate. I just extra up your RSS feed to my MSN Information Reader. Searching for ahead to studying extra from you later on!…

    Reply
  • 9 April 2024 at 10:25 pm
    Permalink

    What Is Sugar Defender? Sugar Defender is a natural blood sugar support formula created by Tom Green. It is based on scientific breakthroughs and clinical studies.

    Reply
  • 16 April 2024 at 5:32 am
    Permalink

    I was suggested this web site by my cousin. I am not sure whether this post is written by him as no one else know such detailed about my problem. You are incredible! Thanks!

    Reply
  • 16 April 2024 at 11:26 pm
    Permalink

    I’ve been surfing on-line greater than three hours nowadays, but I by no means discovered any interesting article like yours. It?¦s pretty worth enough for me. In my view, if all web owners and bloggers made excellent content material as you did, the internet might be a lot more useful than ever before.

    Reply
  • 25 April 2024 at 10:57 am
    Permalink

    We’re a group of volunteers and starting a brand new scheme in our community. Your site provided us with helpful info to paintings on. You’ve performed an impressive task and our entire group will likely be thankful to you.

    Reply
  • 30 April 2024 at 4:44 pm
    Permalink

    I savour, result in I found just what I was having a look for. You have ended my 4 day lengthy hunt! God Bless you man. Have a nice day. Bye

    Reply
  • 1 May 2024 at 5:45 am
    Permalink

    This is very interesting, You are a very skilled blogger. I have joined your rss feed and look forward to seeking more of your excellent post. Also, I have shared your site in my social networks!

    Reply

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *